1 Introduction

It is well known that multinational enterprises (MNEs) take advantage of differences in corporate tax rates and preferential tax measures provided by various countries. In particular, it has been reported that MNEs often artificially shift their profits across countries to avoid taxation (Huizinga & Laeven, 2008; Egger et al., 2010; Zucman, 2014; Davies et al., 2018; Tørsløv et al., 2020). For example, according to the estimation of Tørsløv et al. (2020), more than $600 billion, which was close to 40% of multinational profits, was shifted to tax havens in 2015.Footnote 1 Such huge profit-shifting is basically conducted via “transfer pricing” of intra-firm transactions across countries which account for more than 60% of world trade. With respect to the prices of goods and services within a firm (i.e., transfer prices), there is no market mechanism. Thus, MNEs can manipulate transfer prices for tax planning.

The member countries of Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) have cooperated in efforts to tackle this problem by setting guidelines for transfer pricing and carrying out the Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) project.Footnote 2 OECD (2017) stipulates

When independent enterprises transact with each other, the conditions of their commercial and financial relations (e.g., the price of goods transferred or services provided and the conditions of the transfer or provision) ordinarily are determined by market forces. (Chapter I, p. 33)

These market-driven conditions are codified into the “arm’s length principle (ALP),” which is found in Article 9 of the OECD Model Tax Convention. The ALP is the framework for bilateral treaties between not only OECD member countries but also many non-OECD countries. The application of ALP has received substantial attention in the context of international taxation.Footnote 3 In fact, three out of fifteen actions of the BEPS projects deal with issues on transfer pricing and action 8 particularly targets transfer pricing on intangible transactions based on ALP.Footnote 4

As a method of exercising the ALP, the comparable uncontrolled price (CUP) method is considered ideal. It suggests that tax authorities audit tax avoidance behaviors by comparing the prices used in intra-firm transactions with those of similarly uncontrolled transactions between independent parties, i.e., arm’s length prices (OECD, 2017).

Reality, unfortunately, is not as simple. In particular, it is very difficult to audit intra-firm transfers of intangibles because of the following ambiguous nature of intangibles.Footnote 5 First, it is easy to shift intangibles across countries without having a substantial physical presence in transfer destinations. Thus, MNEs tend to locate their intangibles in tax havens to minimize their tax payments.Footnote 6 For instance, profits shifted to Ireland via royalties accounted for approximately 23% of Ireland’s annual GDP between 2010 and 2015.Footnote 7 Second and more importantly, finding appropriate fees or royalties for intangibles is difficult. As pointed out by the OECD (2017), “Tax administrations should not automatically assume that associated enterprises have sought to manipulate their profits. There may be a genuine difficulty in accurately determining a market price in the absence of market forces or when adopting a particular commercial strategy.”

In the case of transactions of intangibles, therefore, it is difficult to apply the CUP method.Footnote 8 In practice, practitioners heavily rely on a different method called the transactional net margin (TNM) method because of its ease of use.Footnote 9 According to the US Internal Revenue Service, the most frequently used transfer pricing method for both the sales of tangibles and intangibles in advance pricing agreements (APAs) is the comparable profits method or the TNM method, which accounted for 89% in 2016.Footnote 10 The Agency, Japan also reports that the share of the TNM method in mutual agreement procedures closed during the 2019 operation year was 59%.Footnote 11 Despite the fact that different methods of the ALP are used, the extant literature ignores how MNEs determine their transfer pricing via intangible assets under different methods of the ALP.

Against this background, we theoretically explore the relationship between the ALP and MNEs’ technology transfers through patent licensing. Specifically, we investigate how the ALP affects MNE’s licensing strategy and welfare in the presence of a tax haven. On one hand, if the MNE decides to license its technology to unrelated firms, then a comparable transaction appears, and the CUP method becomes applicable. Thus, the MNE needs to set the same royalty for both related and unrelated parties. On the other hand, if the MNE transfers its technology only internally, then there is no comparable transaction and the tax authority relies on the TNM method. When making a licensing decision, the MNE faces a trade-off between the license revenues from the unrelated parties and the greater opportunity for profit-shifting to a tax haven via transfer pricing. Although the MNE always licenses its technology to the local firm without the ALP, the MNE may terminate technology patent with the ALP when tax avoidance opportunity under TNM method is huge or licensing revenues from the local firm are small. Thus, the very presence of the ALP may affect the MNE’s licensing decisions and welfare.

We contribute to transfer pricing literature by capturing this aspect of profit-shifting using intangibles. We explicitly model the determination of transfer prices according to the ALP and show that the ALP increases tax revenues while potentially harming consumers. As a result, the ALP can worsen economic welfare.Footnote 12 Specifically, we demonstrate that the mechanisms of the negative impacts depend on the market structure. If the MNE and the local firm do not compete in the final-good market, the ALP can deteriorate domestic welfare when the MNE does not license its technology because the local firm’s production improvement is not realized. If the MNE and the local firm compete in the market, however, the ALP can decrease domestic welfare when the MNE licenses its patent to the local firm.Footnote 13 This is because the MNE produces less to increase the local firm’s revenues and consequently larger MNE’s revenues in a tax haven via licensing revenues from the local firm. These results indicate market competition plays a critical role in determining welfare impacts.

Many studies about patent licensing have assumed licensing either by means of a per-unit royalty or a fixed fee alone. However, as documented by San Martin and Saracho (2010), most license contracts have adopted the ad valorem scheme for royalty payments instead of a per-unit royalty or a fixed fee. In our analysis, therefore, we focus on ad valorem royalties as licensing payments. Moreover, despite the fact that licensing improves production costs, the interaction between patent licensing and the market has been largely overlooked, because extant literature has often considered only perfectly competitive markets. Our model of imperfect competition can capture this interaction.

Furthermore, we examine the case of per-unit royalty to emphasize transfer pricing under different modes of royalty. We show that the results in the case of an ad valorem royalty contrast strikingly with those in the case of a per-unit royalty. Without market competition between the MNE and the local firm, the ALP resulting in no licensing can worsen domestic welfare because of smaller consumer surplus in the case of an ad valorem royalty. However, such ALP benefits the domestic country in the case of a per-unit royalty because the effective marginal cost for the local firm remains the same and there is no impact on consumer surplus. Moreover, with market interaction between firms, the ALP leading to no licensing benefits consumers in the case of an ad valorem royalty whereas it harms consumers in the case of a per-unit royalty. The reason of consumer-hurting ALP under a per-unit royalty is that the ALP ending up with TNM method removes the MNE’s strategic use of royalty setting which induces the MNE to produce more. These results also imply that welfare effect of the ALP depends on the type of royalty choice as well.

Currently, the ALP is the international transfer pricing regulation to which both OECD and non-OECD member countries have agreed. However, theoretical studies which basically focus on transfer pricing regulation itself are rather limited (Samuelson, 1982; Raimondos-Møller & Scharf, 2002; Bauer & Langenmayr, 2013; Choe & Matsushima, 2013; Keuschnigg & Devereux, 2013; Behrens et al., 2014; Choi et al., 2018, 2020) and the most of them are concerned with only the CUP method.Footnote 14 Additionally, the theoretical analysis of profit-shifting via intangibles has to date been limited only a few studies, including those of Juranek et al. (2018), Juranek et al. (2018), and Hopland et al. (2019). They incorporated royalty payments in their analysis but they did not consider licensing to external firms. Hence, the choice between the CUP and the TNM method, which is the focus of our analysis, was not investigated. To our knowledge, the TNM method has never been dealt with in the theoretical literature on transfer pricing.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a basic setup with licensing by means of ad valorem royalties and analyzes how the ALP (i.e., the CUP and TNM methods) affects MNEs’ incentives to licensing in the presence of a tax haven. In the basic model, the good produced by the licensee is not substitutable with the good produced by the MNE. Section 3 explores the effects of the ALP on domestic welfare with a tax haven. Section 4 extends the basic model to examine substitutability of the goods. Section 5 considers the case of per-unit royalty and makes a comparison. Section 6 concludes the paper.

2 Basic model

Consider the world composed of a domestic country, a foreign country, and another foreign country, labeled D, F, and H, respectively. Country H is a tax haven. Its corporate tax rate is lower than that of country D and is normalized to zero. We assume for simplicity that there is no source tax on royalty payments.Footnote 15 There is a single MNE, the headquarters of which is located in country F . There is a single local firm (called firm Y) in country D. Firm X, a subsidiary of the MNE located in country D, and firm Y, respectively, produce goods X and Y. The two goods are independent and not substitutable.Footnote 16 Each firm is a monopolist in country D. Because we are primarily interested in the MNE’s profit-shifting from the domestic country to the tax haven and the domestic welfare consequences of introducing the ALP, we assume that both goods are consumed only in country D. MNE’s decision making on both the transfer price and production is centralized.Footnote 17

On production costs, there is no fixed cost (FC) and the original marginal cost (MC) of producing good i (\(i=X,Y\)) is \(c_{i}\). The MNE owns a technology patent which can reduce MCs. Although the two goods are not substitutes, the patented technology is assumed to be applied to the production of both goods. With the patent, each firm can reduce its MC from \(c_{i}\) to zero. Thus, firm X’s MC is always zero, whereas firm Y’s MC is zero only when the patent is granted to the local firm. We assume that the licensing contract is by means of ad valorem royalties on revenue basis. The MNE offers ad valorem royalties \(r_{x}\) for internal licensing (i.e., licensing to firm X) and \(r_{y}\) for external licensing (i.e., licensing to firm Y), respectively.

Let \(\pi _{ic_{{}}}\) denote the monopoly profits when MC of good i (\(i=X,Y\) ) with its MC \(c_{i}\). Since the internal licensing always occurs, firm X ’s profits are always \(\pi _{x0}\). Firm Y’s profits depend on whether licensing takes place or not. The profits are \(\pi _{yc}\) without licensing and \(\pi _{y0}\) with licensing, respectively.

We solve the following three-stage game. In the first stage, the MNE determines its internal and external royalty rates. The MNE specifically makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer to firm Y.Footnote 18 After observing the royalty rates, firm Y decides whether to accept the license contract. Finally, firms X and Y produce and supply their products in country D.

2.1 The benchmark case: without a tax haven

To clarify the effects of a tax haven and the ALP, this subsection analyzes the case without the tax haven. We assume that the domestic corporate tax rate, t, and the foreign corporate tax rate are the same.Footnote 19

The MNE has a patent which reduces MC from \(c_{i}\) to 0. Therefore, the subsidiary’s MC is always 0, whereas the local firm’s MC is either \(c_{y}\) or 0. If the MNE grants a license to the local firm, the local firm pays a license fee to the MNE. The royalty rate of the license is \(r_{y}\in [0,1]\). Formally, the post-tax profits can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{M}^{{}}&=(1-t)(\pi _{x0}^{{}}+\lambda r_{y}\pi _{y0}^{{}}), \end{aligned}$$
(1)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{y}^{{}}&=(1-t)\{\lambda (1-r_{y})\pi _{y0}^{{}}+(1-\lambda )\pi _{yc}\}, \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(\lambda\) is a binary variable which takes one if the external licensing arises and zero otherwise.Footnote 20 It should be noted that a change in t does not affect output levels.

Given Eq. (2), the local firm accepts the licensing offer if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \Pi _{y}^{{}}\right| _{\lambda =1}\ge \left. \Pi _{y}^{{}}\right| _{\lambda =0}\iff r_{y}\le 1-\frac{\pi _{yc}}{\pi _{y0}^{{}}}=\frac{\Omega }{\pi _{y0}^{{}}}, \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(\Omega \equiv \pi _{y0}^{{}}-\pi _{yc}>0\). Since the two firms do not interact in the markets, the MNE is always willing to license its technology to the local firm. From Eq. (1), it is always optimal for the MNE to obtain license revenues by setting the highest royalty subject to Eq. (3), \(r_{y}=\Omega /\pi _{y0}^{{}}\equiv r_{y}^{*}(<1)\). In other words, the MNE will set the royalty rate such that license revenues equal \(\Omega .\)

In equilibrium, the post-tax profits become

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{M}^{*}=(1-t)\left( \pi _{x0}^{{}}+\Omega \right) \text { and}\quad \Pi _{y}^{*}=(1-t)(1-r_{y}^{*})\pi _{y0}^{{}}=(1-t)\pi _{yc}. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

As seen in the above equation, the optimal license contract makes the local firm indifferent between with and without licensing.

2.2 A tax haven without the ALP

We now introduce a tax haven into the analysis. We assume that the MNE establishes a shell company, firm S, in country H without any cost. Obviously, transferring the patent to the shell company is the optimal strategy for the MNE, because it can make more profits in the tax haven not only by profit-shifting from firm X but also by license revenues from firm Y. We assume for simplicity that the headquarters transfers the patent to the shell company free of charge.Footnote 21 The profits of the MNE and firm Y are, respectively, given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{M}^{TH}&=(1-t)(1-r_{x}^{TH})\pi _{x0}^{{}}+r_{x}^{TH}\pi _{x0}^{{}}+r_{y}^{TH}\pi _{y0}^{{}}, \\ \Pi _{y}^{TH}&=(1-t)(1-r_{y}^{TH})\pi _{y0}^{{}}, \end{aligned}$$

where the first term of \(\Pi _{M}^{TH}\) is the post-tax profits of firm X and the second and third terms are the license revenues from firms X and Y recorded in country H.

We first consider the case without the ALP. In this case, the MNE can set ad valorem royalties without any constraint. The optimal royalty rate is one with which all profits of firm X are shifted to firm S. Thus, \(r_{x}^{*TH}=1\), whereas the arm’s length royalty rate is the same as the benchmark case (i.e., \(r_{y}^{*TH}=r_{y}^{*}\)).

As a result, we obtain the same licensing strategy as the benchmark case in equilibrium. This is because the country where the MNE reports the tax base simply changes from country D to country H. Because the corporate tax is proportionally imposed on the profits, the tax rates never affect the licensing strategy. Therefore, the post-tax profits are computed as

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{M}^{*TH}=\pi _{x0}^{{}}+\Omega ,\quad \text {and}\quad \Pi _{y}^{*TH}=(1-t)\pi _{yc}\left( =\Pi _{y}^{*}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(5)

2.3 A tax haven with the ALP

Finally, we investigate the effect of the ALP in the presence of a tax haven. The ALP restricts the MNE’s profit-shifting strategy through one of two methods, the CUP method and the TNM method. The TNM method examines the profit-level indicator (PLI), defined as net profits relative to an appropriate base (e.g., sales) that a taxpayer realizes from a controlled transaction. With the TNM method, the PLI of the taxpayer from the controlled transaction should be equal to the PLI obtained in a comparable transaction by an independent enterprise (i.e., a reference firm).

First, if the MNE licenses the technology to the local firm, the CUP method applies. The MNE is unable to price-discriminate because of the emergence of a comparable transaction and arm’s length royalty. Put differently, the MNE must set a uniform royalty rate, \(r^{CUP}\). The MNE’s problem can be stated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \underset{r^{CUP}}{Max}\ \ \Pi _{M}^{CUP}=\, & {} (1-t)(1-r^{CUP})\pi _{x0}^{{}}+r^{CUP}(\pi _{x0}^{{}}+\pi _{y0}^{{}}) \\=\,& {} (1-t)\left( 1+\frac{t}{1-t}r^{CUP}\right) \pi _{x0}^{{}}+r^{CUP}\pi _{y0}^{{}} \end{aligned}$$

subject to

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \Pi _{y}^{CUP}\right| _{\lambda =1}\ge \left. \Pi _{y}^{CUP}\right| _{\lambda =0}\iff r\le 1-\frac{\pi _{yc}}{\pi _{y0}^{{}}}=r_{y}^{*}(<1). \end{aligned}$$

Because \(\Pi _{M}^{CUP}\) is strictly increasing in \(r^{CUP}\), the optimal royalty rate is given by \(r^{*CUP}=r_{y}^{*}\). This strategy generates the following post-tax profits:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{M}^{*CUP}= \,& {} (1-t)\left[ 1+\frac{t}{1-t}\left( 1-\frac{\pi _{yc}}{ \pi _{y0}^{{}}}\right) \right] \pi _{x0}^{{}}+\Omega \end{aligned}$$
(6)
$$\begin{aligned}=\, & {} (1-t)\left[ 1+\frac{t}{1-t}\left( \frac{\Omega }{\pi _{y0}^{{}}}\right) \right] \pi _{x0}^{{}}+\Omega \text {,} \nonumber \\ \Pi _{y}^{*CUP}=\, & {} (1-t)\pi _{yc}\left( =\Pi _{y}^{*}=\Pi _{y}^{*TH}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(7)

Note that the imposition of the ALP does not lead to the elimination of profit-shifting.Footnote 22 As seen in Eq. (6), the MNE shifts only a part of its profits to the tax haven. As discussed in Sect. 2.1, \(r^{*CUP}\) is determined only by the market condition of good Y. This means that the MNE’s global post-tax profits under the CUP method increase as \(\Omega\) increases.

Alternatively, if the MNE does not license its technology, no comparable transaction appears. Hence, the royalty rate is regulated by the TNM method. Under TNM method, the tax authority compares MNEs’ PLI with a reference firm’s PLI.Footnote 23 The selection criteria of the reference firm are based upon an evaluation of the functional risks of the taxpayer and the reference firm (e.g., R&D risk and credit risk). This implies that they may not operate in the same industry. Moreover, a particular taxpayer can propose a reference firm for the TNM method in an APA.Footnote 24 However, the tax authorities still reserve the right to reject the APA application and can choose the reference firm to some extent.

Given the above features, with the TNM method, the royalty rate \(r_{x}^{TNM}\) is set such that the PLI of firm X equals the PLI of the reference firm which is exogenously given by \(1-\eta\) in this subsection.Footnote 25 That is, \((p_{x}x-r_{x}^{TNM}p_{x}x)/p_{x}x=1-\eta\) where \(p_{x}\) and x are the price and the output level of good X. Then, \(r_{x}^{*TNM}=\eta\) holds. Thus, we have the following post-tax profits under the TNM method:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{M}^{*TNM}=\, & {} (1-t)(1-\eta )\pi _{x0}^{{}}+\eta \pi _{x0}^{{}} \nonumber \\= \,& {} (1-t)\pi _{x0}^{{}}+t\eta \pi _{x0}^{{}}, \end{aligned}$$
(8)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{y}^{*TNM}= \,& {} (1-t)\pi _{yc}^{{}}\left( =\Pi _{y}^{*}=\Pi _{y}^{*TH}=\Pi _{y}^{*CUP}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(9)

A comparison of the two post-tax profits reveals the condition used to determine whether to license the technology. Formally, the MNE grants the license to the local firm if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \Pi _{M}\equiv \,& {} \Pi _{M}^{*CUP}-\Pi _{M}^{*TNM} \end{aligned}$$
(10)
$$\begin{aligned}= \,& {} \left\{ (1-t)\left[ 1+\frac{t}{1-t}\left( \frac{\Omega }{\pi _{y0}^{{}}} \right) \right] \pi _{x0}^{{}}+\Omega \right\} -\left\{ (1-t)\pi _{x0}^{{}}+t\eta \pi _{x0}^{{}}\right\} \end{aligned}$$
(11)
$$\begin{aligned}= \,& {} \Omega -t\left[ \eta -\underset{=r^{*CUP}=r_{y}^{*}}{\underbrace{ \frac{\Omega }{\pi _{y0}^{{}}}}}\right] \pi _{x0}^{{}}>0. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

We can easily confirm that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Delta \Pi _{M}}{\partial \eta }<0,\frac{\partial \Delta \Pi _{M}}{\partial \Omega }>0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, given the other parameters, we can define a threshold of \(\eta\), \(\eta ^{L}\), such that the MNE is indifferent to licensing and non-licensing. Licensing arises if and only if \(\eta \le \eta ^{L}(\equiv \Omega (\pi _{y0}^{{}}+t\pi _{x0}^{{}})/(t\pi _{x0}^{{}}\pi _{y0}^{{}}))\). It is obvious that \(\eta ^{L}>\Omega /\pi _{y0}^{{}}=r_{y}^{*}\).

Thus, the following proposition is established.

Proposition 1

The introduction of the ALP in the presence of the tax haven results in non-licensing if \(\eta\) is sufficiently large or if \(\Omega\) is sufficiently small.

The proposition is intuitive. The MNE faces a trade-off between license revenues from the local firm and the profit-shifting from its subsidiary to the tax haven. The latter is likely to dominate the former as \(\eta\) becomes larger and \(\Omega\) (or \(c_{y}\)) becomes smaller.

3 Welfare analysis

In this section, we consider the effects of the ALP on domestic welfare. Following the previous literature (e.g., Kind et al., 2005), we assume that the MNE is owned by residents in the foreign country. Thus, domestic welfare comprises consumer surplus, firm Y’s profits, and domestic tax revenues.Footnote 26 Note that the sum of firm Y’s post-tax profits and tax revenues from firm Y is always constant and equal to \(\pi _{yc}\). Consumer surplus in the market of good X also remains constant. Thus, a change in domestic welfare is simply the sum of a change in consumer surplus in the market of good Y, \(CS_{y}\), and a change in tax revenues from the MNE, \(TR_{x}\). Obviously, \(CS_{y}\) is larger with licensing than without it.

In the absence of the ALP, domestic welfare with the tax haven is always less than that of the benchmark case, because the presence of the tax haven does not affect the licensing strategy. Instead, it leads to leakage of tax revenues from the domestic country to the tax haven. Thus, the presence of the tax haven is always harmful for the domestic country.

We now investigate the welfare effects of the ALP in the presence of the tax haven. To this end, we compare domestic welfare between the two regimes with and without the ALP. If the introduction of the ALP does not affect the licensing strategy of the MNE, that is, if the MNE is still engaged in licensing with the ALP (which is the CUP method in this case), the impact of the ALP is straightforward. Obviously, \(CS_{y}\) is not affected. Under the CUP method, MNE’s profit-shifting is restricted, which means that \(TR_{x}\) increases. Thus, the ALP increases domestic welfare by \(t(1-r^{*CUP})\pi _{x0}^{{}}\), implying \(W^{*CUP}>W^{*TH}\) holds. However, if the ALP changes the licensing strategies, that is, if the MNE is not engaged in licensing under the ALP, a trade-off arises. On one hand, the ALP decreases MNE’s profit-shifting to the tax haven and hence \(TR_{x}\) increases. On the other hand, non-licensing lowers productivity of the local firm and hence \(CS_{y}\) decreases. Thus, \(W^{*TNM}>W^{*TH}\) may or may not hold. We then obtain the following lemma.

Lemma 1

While \(W^{*CUP}>W^{*TH}\) holds, the comparison between \(W^{*TNM}\) and \(W^{*TH}\) is ambiguous.

\(W^{*TNM}\) is decreasing in \(\eta\) while both \(W^{*CUP}\) and \(W^{*TH}\) are independent of \(\eta\). Thus, \(W^{*TNM}>W^{*CUP}\) and \(W^{*TNM}>W^{*TH}\) are likely if \(\eta\) is close to 0 and vice versa if \(\eta\) is close to 1. Recall that whether licensing occurs or not depends on \(\Delta \Pi _{M}^{{}}(\equiv \Pi _{M}^{*CUP}-\Pi _{M}^{*TNM})\) and hence licensing occurs if and only if \(\eta \le \eta ^{L}\).

The following computation reflecting linear demands clarifies lemma 1. Assume that the inverse demands are given by

$$\begin{aligned} p_{x}=A-ax\ \ \ \ \text {and}\ \ \ \ p_{y}=B-by. \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Then, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} x^{*TH}= & {} \frac{A}{2a},y^{*TH}=\frac{B}{2b},\quad \\ x^{*TNM}= & {} \frac{A}{2a},y^{*TNM}=\frac{B-c_{y}}{2b}. \end{aligned}$$

First, domestic welfare without the ALP, \(W^{*TH}\), is compared to that with the TNM method, \(W^{*TNM}\):

$$\begin{aligned} W^{*TNM}-W^{*TH}&=CS_{y}^{*TNM}-CS_{y}^{*TH}+t(1-\eta ) \frac{A^{2}}{4a} \end{aligned}$$
(14)
$$\begin{aligned}&=-\frac{c_{y}(2B-c_{y})}{8b}+t(1-\eta )\frac{A^{2}}{4a}\ge 0\iff \eta \le 1-\frac{ac_{y}(2B-c_{y})}{2tbA^{2}}\equiv \eta ^{W}. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

\(W^{*TNM}<W^{*TH}\) holds if and only if \(\eta >\eta ^{W}\), because greater \(\eta\) results in more opportunity of profit-shifting for the MNE. The increase in tax revenues caused by the ALP (which is the TNM method in this case) is not large enough to cover the decrease in consumer surplus in the market of good Y.

Thus, we have two cases. With \(\eta ^{L}<\eta ^{W}\), the ALP may enhance domestic welfare even if licensing does not occur in the presence of the ALP. More specifically, if \(\eta ^{L}<\eta <\eta ^{W}\), domestic welfare increases even without licensing. With \(\eta ^{L}>\eta ^{W}\), however, the ALP improves domestic welfare if and only if licensing arises (recall Lemma 1).

We can thus derive the condition under which \(\eta ^{L}<\eta ^{W}\) holds:

$$\begin{aligned} \eta ^{L}<\eta ^{W}\iff t>\frac{aB^{2}(2B^{2}+2Bc_{y}-c_{y}^{2})}{ 2bA^{2}(B-c_{y})^{2}}\equiv {\underline{t}}. \end{aligned}$$

This is illustrated in Fig. 1. Therefore, if licensing does not occur in the presence of the ALP, the ALP is necessarily harmful to the domestic country with \(t<{\underline{t}}\) but may be beneficial with \(t>{\underline{t}}\). When t is high, the tax revenues may be large enough to offset the consumer loss.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Licensing decision and welfare in equilibrium

The results are illustrated in Figs. 2 and 3.Footnote 27 The figures show how \(\eta\) affects the MNE’s licensing strategy and domestic welfare. Figure 2 is drawn with \(t=0.3<\) \({\underline{t}}\), meaning \(\eta ^{L}>\eta ^{W}\). If \(\eta <\eta ^{L}\), the MNE has an incentive for licensing and domestic welfare is larger with the ALP (i.e., the CUP method) than without. If \(\eta >\eta ^{L}\), on the other hand, licensing does not occur and domestic welfare is smaller with the ALP (i.e., the TNM method) than without. Thus, if the MNE terminates licensing because of the ALP, the domestic country loses. Figure 3 is drawn with \(t=0.5>\) \({\underline{t}}\), meaning \(\eta ^{L}<\eta ^{W}\). In this case, even if the ALP leads the MNE to stop licensing, the domestic country gains with \(\eta <\eta ^{W}\).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Welfare effects of the ALP with \(t=0.3\)

Fig. 3
figure 3

Welfare effects of the ALP with \(t=0.5\)

These results are summarized in the following proposition.

Proposition 2

Suppose that the ALP is introduced in the presence of a tax haven. The ALP improves domestic welfare if licensing occurs. More specifically, domestic welfare improves if and only if \(\eta <\max \{\eta ^{L},\eta ^{W}\}\).

We next take the choice of \(\eta\) into account. As described in Sect. 2, APAs are often made. In its scheme, a tax payer can pre-consult the tax authority about the reference firm. Although the government cannot freely choose the reference firm or \(\eta\), it still has freedom of choice to some extent. Given the fact, we specifically assume that the government can choose \(\eta \in [{\underline{\eta }},{\overline{\eta }}]\) where \(0< {\underline{\eta }}<{\overline{\eta }}<1\).

We consider an extended game where in Stage 0, prior to the MNE’s decision on royalty rates, the domestic government chooses \(\eta\) from a certain range to maximize domestic welfare. If \({\underline{\eta }}<\eta ^{L}\), the government sets \(\eta\) to induce licensing. As long as licensing is induced, the size of \(\eta\) does not matter. This is because domestic welfare with licensing is independent of \(\eta\). If \({\underline{\eta }}\ge \eta ^{L}\) on the other hand, the government chooses \(\eta ={\underline{\eta }}\). Note that the ALP harms the domestic country if \({\underline{\eta }}>\max \{\eta ^{W},\eta ^{L}\}\).

Thus, we have the following proposition.

Proposition 3

Suppose that the government chooses \(\eta\) from the domain \([\underline{ \eta },{\overline{\eta }}]\) where \(0<{\underline{\eta }}<{\overline{\eta }}<1\). The optimal royalty rate \(\eta ^{*}\) is given by \(\eta ^{*}= {\underline{\eta }}\) if \(\eta ^{L}\le {\underline{\eta }}\) and \(\underline{\eta }\le \eta ^{*}\le \min \{\eta ^{L},{\overline{\eta }}\}\) if \(\underline{ \eta }<\eta ^{L}\).

This proposition says that the domestic government should choose a reference firm which leads to licensing. However, if licensing cannot be induced with a possible choice set of reference firms, the domestic government should choose a reference firm with the lowest \(\eta\). Note that licensing is more likely to occur with a lower \(\eta\). Thus, whether or not licensing is induced, the domestic government should choose a reference firm with the lowest \(\eta\), i.e., the most stringent regulation.

4 Substitutable goods

In the basic model, to clarify our point, we have assumed that both goods X and Y are not at all substitutable. In this section, we consider the case in which the two goods are substitutable. We show that the results with substitutable goods contrast clearly with those in the basic model.

We assume that the MNE and the local firm produce a homogeneous good and are engaged in Cournot competition. We also assume the following linear demand:

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{p}}=A-a({\widetilde{x}}+{\widetilde{y}}). \end{aligned}$$
(16)

One may think that the MNE’s subsidiary exits the market after providing the license, enabling the local firm to earn the monopoly profits and extracting possibly a higher rent through a license fee. As Mukherjee (2007) points out, however, the commitment by the MNE for not entering the market may not be credible. In our analysis, therefore, we focus on the Cournot duopoly.

4.1 A tax haven with the ALP

In the case of non-licensing with the ALP, the MNE has to set the internal royalty rate equal to the comparable value \(\eta\). The profits are

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{TNM}= \,& {} (1-t)(1-\eta ){\widetilde{p}}{\widetilde{x}}+\eta {\widetilde{p}}{\widetilde{x}} \nonumber \\=\, & {} (1-t+\eta t){\widetilde{p}}{\widetilde{x}}, \nonumber \\ {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{y}^{TNM}=\, & {} (1-t)\left( {\widetilde{p}}-c_{y}\right) {\widetilde{y}}. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

Noting that the outputs are independent of the internal royalty rate, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{x}}^{*TNM}=\frac{A+c_{y}}{3a},\quad {\widetilde{y}}^{*TNM}= \frac{A-2c_{y}}{3a}. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Thus, the MNE’s profits with the TNM method become

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{*TNM}= \,& {} (1-t+t\eta )\frac{(A+c_{y})^{2}}{9a}, \\ {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{y}^{*TNM}= \,& {} (1-t)\frac{(A-2c_{y})^{2}}{9a}\equiv {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{y}^{*}. \end{aligned}$$

In the case of licensing with the ALP, the MNE cannot price-discriminate between its subsidiary and the local firm.

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{CUP}=\, & {} (1-t)(1-{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP}){\widetilde{p}} {\widetilde{x}}+{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP}{\widetilde{p}}{\widetilde{x}}+{\widetilde{r}} ^{CUP}{\widetilde{p}}{\widetilde{y}} \nonumber \\= \,& {} (1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP}){\widetilde{p}}{\widetilde{x}}+{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP} {\widetilde{p}}{\widetilde{y}}, \nonumber \\ {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{y}^{CUP}= \,& {} (1-t)(1-{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP}){\widetilde{p}} {\widetilde{y}}. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

Then, the outputs and profits are given by

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{x}}^{CUP}= & {} \frac{\{(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP})-{\widetilde{r}} ^{CUP}\}A}{\{3(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP})-{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP}\}a},\quad {\widetilde{y}}^{CUP}=\frac{(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP})A}{\{3(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}} ^{CUP})-{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP}\}a}, \\ {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{CUP}= & {} \frac{(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP})^{3}A^{2}}{ \{3(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP})-{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP}\}^{2}a},{\widetilde{\Pi }} _{y}^{CUP}=(1-t)\frac{(1-{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP})(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}} ^{CUP})^{2}A^{2}}{\{3(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP})-{\widetilde{r}}^{CUP}\}^{2}a}. \end{aligned}$$

We can verify \({\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{CUP}\) is increasing in \({\widetilde{r}} ^{CUP}\) but \({\widetilde{\Pi }}_{y}^{CUP}\) is decreasing in \({\widetilde{r}} ^{CUP}\). Thus, the optimal royalty rate, \({\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP}\), satisfies the following condition:

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{y}^{*CUP}=(1-t)\frac{(1-{\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP})(1-t+t {\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP})^{2}A^{2}}{\{3(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP})- {\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP}\}^{2}a}=(1-t)\frac{(A-2c_{y})^{2}}{9a}=\widetilde{ \Pi }_{y}^{*}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \({\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP}\), the MNE’s profits with the CUP method become

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{*CUP}=\frac{(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP})^{3}A^{2}}{\{3(1-t+t{\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP})-{\widetilde{r}}^{*CUP}\}^{2}a}. \end{aligned}$$

The relative magnitude of \({\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{*CUP}\) and \(\widetilde{ \Pi }_{M}^{*TNM}\) is ambiguous. We can confirm that \(\Delta \widetilde{ \Pi }_{M}(\equiv {\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{*CUP}-{\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{*TNM})<0\) is possible only if \(c_{y}\) is small. Small \(c_{y}\) implies that licensing is not very attractive to the MNE, because the smaller the \(c_{y}\) , the smaller the license revenues.

4.2 Welfare comparison

We examine how domestic welfare changes when the ALP is introduced in the presence of a tax haven. Since the presence of the ALP does not affect the profits of the local firm, a change in domestic welfare is measured by the sum of changes in tax revenues from the MNE, \(\textrm{TR}_{x}\), and in consumer surplus, CS. The ALP necessarily makes the tax revenues from the MNE positive. Thus, we check how CS changes as a result of the ALP.

We can prove the following lemma.Footnote 28

Lemma 2

(i) \({\widetilde{x}}^{*CUP}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*CUP}<{\widetilde{x}}^{*TNM}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*TNM}\), (ii) \({\widetilde{x}}^{*CUP}+{\widetilde{y}} ^{*CUP}<{\widetilde{x}}^{*TH}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*TH}\) if \(t\le \frac{ 1}{3}\), and (iii) \({\widetilde{x}}^{*TH}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*TH}< {\widetilde{x}}^{*TNM}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*TNM}\).

In the presence of the ALP, the total supply of the good is greater without licensing than with licensing (see Lemma 2 (i)). This seems surprising because the total output is less with licensing despite the fact that licensing leads both firms to produce the good with zero MC. The intuition is as follows. When the goods are substitutes, the MNE decreases the output of its subsidiary to increase the output of the local firm and the price and hence the license revenues from the local firm. The negative effect on the total output caused by the MNE’s centralized decision with licensing by means of ad valorem royalties dominates the positive effect of the cost reduction of the local firm.

Lemma 2 (ii) and (iii) say that CS without the ALP may be larger than CS with the CUP method but is smaller than CS with the TNM method. Thus, as a result of the introduction of the ALP, consumers may lose if licensing occurs but gain if it does not.

The above strategic channel of ad valorem royalty on production is analyzed by San Martin and Saracho (2010), but our model newly shows the impact of the ALP on licensing behavior. Without the ALP, external royalty has a collusive effect. However, with the ALP, such collusive effect may no longer exist when the MNE decides not to license to the local firm.

Given the importance of tax avoidance via intangible asset, the welfare effect of licensing under the ALP is interesting to investigate. Noting that the ALP increases tax revenues, we can establish the following proposition.

Proposition 4

Suppose that the MNE’s subsidiary and the local firm compete in the market. The ALP may harm consumers and worsen domestic welfare if the MNE continues licensing to the local firm, but benefits consumers and improves domestic welfare if the MNE terminates licensing to the local firm.

Figures 4, 5, and 6 illustrate whether the introduction of the ALP improves domestic welfare.Footnote 29 Each figure is drawn with a different tax rate. \({\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{*TNM}\) is more likely to exceed \({\widetilde{\Pi }}_{M}^{*CUP}\) if \(\eta\) is relatively large and t is relatively small. In the presence of the ALP, licensing occurs if and only if \(\eta <\eta ^{L}\). The ALP always improves domestic welfare in Figs. 4 and 5. If licensing is present under the ALP, the increase in the tax revenues dominates the loss of consumers. However, in Fig. 6, the ALP worsens domestic welfare in the presence of licensing because the loss of consumers actually exceeds the increase in the tax revenues.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Perfect substitutability and welfare effects of the ALP with \(t=0.3\)

Fig. 5
figure 5

Perfect substitutability and welfare effects of the ALP with \(t=0.4\)

Fig. 6
figure 6

Perfect substitutability and welfare effects of the ALP with \(t=0.5\)

Proposition 4 provides us with a new implication on the optimal enforcement of the ALP. As the main purpose of the ALP is to prevent MNEs’ tax avoidance, extant literature regards stricter enforcement of the ALP as a desirable policy, which is captured by a lower \({\overline{\eta }}\) in our model. While this is also true in our basic model, it is not necessarily true with goods substitutability because consumers may lose. Thus, even though choosing a reference firm with a lower \({\overline{\eta }}\) becomes possible thanks to stricter enforcement of the ALP, such a choice does not necessarily imply a welfare improvement in non-tax haven countries.

5 Per-unit royalty

We have investigated transfer pricing with patent licensing by means of ad valorem royalties. In this section, to further emphasize transfer pricing with ad valorem royalties, we consider transfer pricing with patent licensing by means of a per-unit royalty and make a comparison.

The profits with a tax haven are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{M}^{{}}= & {} (1-t)(p_{x}-\upsilon _{x})x+\upsilon _{x}x+\lambda \upsilon _{y}y \\= & {} (1-t)\left( p_{x}+\frac{t\upsilon _{x}}{1-t}\right) x+\lambda \upsilon _{y}y, \\ \Pi _{y}^{{}}= & {} (1-t)\{\lambda (p_{y}-\upsilon _{y})y+(1-\lambda )(p_{y}-c_{y})y\}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\upsilon _{x}\) and \(\upsilon _{y}\) are the per-unit royalty charged by the MNE. With the CUP method, we have \(\upsilon _{x}=\) \(\upsilon _{y}\).

5.1 No substitutability

We begin with the case without substitutability between the MNE’s final good and the local firm’s final good.Footnote 30 As we will see immediately, the introduction of the ALP always improves domestic welfare.

First, suppose that the ALP is absent. Then, the MNE has an incentive to grant the patent to the local firm, because the MNE can price-discriminate between its subsidiary and the local firm. On the one hand, the per-unit royalty for the local firm is equal to its MC, \(c_{y}\) to extract all the increased revenues.Footnote 31 On the other hand, as shown in Choi et al. (2020), the per-unit royalty for the subsidiary is equal to the monopoly price of good X which would be charged if the effective MC equals zero. That is, the subsidiary produces the monopoly output level with the effective MC equal to zero and all the profits of the subsidiary are shifted to the tax haven.

Now suppose that the ALP is introduced. In the presence of licensing to the local firm, the CUP method applies, implying that the same per-unit royalty must be set between the subsidiary and the local firm. Appendix B shows that the per-unit royalty equals \(c_{y}\) with the CUP method. Thus, the output of the local firm remains the same, which indicates that consumer surplus in the market of good Y, the revenues of firm Y, and the tax revenues from firm Y do not change. However, as shown in Choi et al. (2020), the output of the subsidiary increases because the MNE cannot shift all the profits of subsidiary to the tax haven and tries to shift more profits by increasing the volume of the MNE’s production. This means two positive effect of the ALP resulting in CUP method. First, likewise in the previous analyses, domestic tax revenues from the MNE, \(TR_{x}\), become positive. In addition, consumer surplus in the market of good X, \(CS_{x}\), increases due to the tax-induced supplies by the MNE. Thus, domestic welfare improves under CUP method.

If the MNE’s licensing to the local firm is terminated as a result of the ALP, the TNM method applies. With the TNM method, the per-unit royalty for the subsidiary, \(\upsilon _{x}\), becomes \(p_{x}\eta\) because we have \((p_{x}x-\upsilon _{x}x)/p_{x}x=1-\eta\). The local firm produces its final good with its original MC to produce good Y, \(c_{y}\). As a result, Eqs. (8) and (9) hold, and we can readily verify that the outputs of goods X and Y do not change. Additionally, since the ALP makes \(TR_{x}\) positive, domestic welfare improves. Thus, we obtain the following proposition.

Proposition 5

(Per-unit royalty) Suppose that the MNE’s subsidiary and the local firm do not compete in the market and licensing contract is based on per-unit basis. The introduction of the ALP in the presence of the tax haven improves domestic welfare whether or not the MNE license its patent to the local firm.

This proposition is in contrast with Proposition 2 which shows the possibility of negative welfare effect of the ALP under TNM method. The difference stems from the nature of supplies by the local firm. In the case of a per-unit royalty, the supplies by the local firm remain constant as per-unit royalty is equal to its MC, and hence the introduction of the ALP necessarily improves domestic welfare by the appearance of tax revenues from the MNE. However, in the case of ad valorem royalty, the local firm’s supplies increase by licensing as ad valorem royalty is proportional to revenues, and the ALP may worsen domestic welfare if the patent is not licensed to the local firm. Overall, patent licensing by means of a per-unit royalty results more likely in welfare improvement.

5.2 Perfect substitutability

Next we consider the case with substitutability to see positive effects of the ALP on consumer and the local firm.

Without the ALP, the MNE always grants patent to the local firm at the per-unit royalty equal to the MC, \(c_{y}\). Unlike no substitutability case, the equilibrium supplies are functions of the tax rate because the MNE’s output decision depends on tax-adjusted MC including the efficiency of tax-savings.Footnote 32 As higher transfer prices induce more profit-shifting and enhance efficiency of tax-savings, the MNE’s outputs increase, and the local firm’s outputs decrease compared to the standard Cournot duopoly.Footnote 33

With the ALP which drops efficiency of the MNE’s tax avoidance, the MNE supplies less and subsequently the local firm supplies more compared to the case without the ALP. With the CUP method, the MNE sets the same per-unit royalty resulting in inefficient tax-savings and an increase in the tax-adjusted MC. With the TNM method, again, we have \(\upsilon _x=p_x\eta\) and such transfer pricing proportional to good price results in the standard Cournot duopoly outcome shown in Eq. (18). Moreover, by the nature of the take-it-or-leave-it offer, the local firm’s supplies do not change between CUP and TNM methods, but increases because of the ALP.

In addition to the above discussion on supplies by each firm, Appendix C shows the following lemma.Footnote 34

Lemma 3

(i) \({\widetilde{x}}^{*TH}>{\widetilde{x}}^{*CUP}>{\widetilde{x}}^{*TNM}\), (ii) \({\widetilde{y}}^{*CUP}={\widetilde{y}}^{*TNM}>{\widetilde{y}} ^{*TH}\), (iii) \({\widetilde{x}}^{*TNM}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*TNM}< {\widetilde{x}}^{*TH}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*TH}\) and (iv) \({\widetilde{x}} ^{*CUP}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*CUP}>{\widetilde{x}}^{*TH}+{\widetilde{y}} ^{*TH}\) if \(\frac{A(2-t)}{7-5t}<c_{y}<\frac{A(1-t)}{2-t}\), while \({\widetilde{x}}^{*CUP}+{\widetilde{y}}^{*CUP}<{\widetilde{x}}^{*TH}+ {\widetilde{y}}^{*TH}\) if \(\frac{A(1-t)}{2-t}<\frac{A(2-t)}{7-5t}\).

The lemma provides three notable results. First, as the profits of the local firm increase as its output increases, the ALP benefits the local firm (see Lemma 3 (ii)). In the previous analyses, no effects of the ALP on the local firm are confirmed. Hence, this positive effect of the ALP on local firm is observed only in the case with a per-unit royalty and perfect substitutability. Moreover, since the profits of the local firm increase, the ALP increases tax revenues not only from the MNE but also from the local firm.

Second, the effects of the ALP under TNM method on consumer are opposite to those in the case of ad valorem royalty. In the case of ad valorem royalty, Lemma 2 (iii) shows that the ALP necessarily benefits consumers if licensing to the local firm is terminated. However, in the case of per-unit royalty, consumers necessarily lose if licensing does not occur with the ALP (see Lemma 3 (iii)). The difference stems from different channels of strategic use of royalty settings without the ALP. With ad valorem royalty, royalties are set such that the MNE’s supplies become less to increase the local firm’s revenues and to extract the increased revenues of the local firm. With per-unit royalty, the royalties are determined such that the MNE produces more to increase intra-firm trade and to shift profits into the tax haven. Hence, termination of the licensing due to the ALP impacts on total supplies in opposite directions.

Finally, although the effect of the ALP on consumers is ambiguous with both licensing by means of ad valorem royalties and licensing by means of a per-unit royalty (see Lemma 2 (ii) and (iii), and Lemma 3 (iii) and (iv)), the magnitude of consumer surplus in the presence of the ALP is also opposite between the two licensing cases as a result of the above pattern of firms’ production. With a per-unit royalty, consumers prefer licensing to non-licensing (see Lemma 3 (i) and (ii)) whereas ad valorem royalties make consumer surplus higher when non-licensing takes place.

Hence, given the positive and negative impacts of the ALP, the ALP may or may not improve domestic welfare. To sum, the following proposition is established.

Proposition 6

(Per-unit royalty) Suppose that the MNE’s subsidiary and the local firm compete in the goods market and licensing contract is based on per-unit basis. The introduction of the ALP in the presence of the tax haven benefits the local firm and increases the tax revenues but may harm consumers. Consumers gain only if the MNE sells the input to the local firm with the ALP.

6 Concluding remarks

This paper has dealt with the MNE’s transfer pricing of intangibles licensed by means of ad valorem royalties. Our focus was on the effects of the ALP on MNE’s licensing strategies and economic welfare in the presence of a tax haven. Specifically, we have explored the CUP and TNM methods as the ALP.

Our findings in the basic model, in which a potential licensee is unrelated to the MNE’s subsidiary, provide two insights. First, the ALP may distort the MNE’s licensing strategy. In the absence of the ALP, the MNE is willing to offer a licensing contract to an unrelated firm regardless of the existence of a tax haven. In the presence of the ALP, however, the MNE may refrain from the offering the contract to eliminate the comparable transaction of licensing, which may enable the MNE to avoid the imposition of the CUP method and enjoy further profit-shifting opportunities from its subsidiary.

Second and more importantly, the disincentivization of licensing may worsen the welfare of high-tax countries. One may expect that anti-tax avoidance policies such as BEPS actions prevent MNEs from profit-shifting and contribute to welfare improvement through an increase in the tax revenue. Our model, however, has shown that such a positive aspect may appear at the expense of consumers, because the MNEs may terminate licensing to remove comparable transactions.

We then investigated the case in which the goods are substitutes as an extension to our basic model. In this case, interestingly enough, consumers may lose even if the licensing still occurs with the ALP. This is because the MNE decreases the output of its subsidiary to take more advantage of the license revenues from the unrelated firm. The point is a strategic effect which is absent in the basic model comes in. As a result, the ALP harms consumers. Thus, the welfare effects of ALP depend on whether or not goods are substitutable.

We have focused on two extreme cases (i.e., non-substitution and perfect substitution) and obtained the distinct results between these cases. In our model, the MNE adjusts a trade-off between the license revenues from the unrelated firm and the greater opportunity for profit-shifting to a tax haven via transfer pricing when offering licensing contracts. The adjustment is most contrasting between the non-substitution case and the perfect substitution case. As shown in Appendix D which examines imperfect substitution, we confirm that the results are robust.

Furthermore, we have examined the case of a per-unit royalty. The results are shown to be in contrast with those in the case of ad valorem royalties. This implies whether the type of licensing contract on royalty payments in question is ad valorem or per-unit royalty could be crucial in evaluating the ALP. Note that we can regard the case of per-unit royalty as the case of tangible inputs. Moreover, we can readily confirm that the results of technology licensing by means of a fixed payment are basically the same as those by means of ad valorem royalties without any substitutability, because there are no strategic interactions via royalty payments in both cases. Thus, licensing scheme also matters in evaluating the ALP.

We use the Cournot model to analyze competition with substitutable products. As demonstrated by Kreps and Scheinkman (1983), we can interpret the Cournot model as a static representation of a two-stage game in which firms first build capacity followed by price competition. For instance, it can be applied to the semi-conductor industry in which firms first build capacity prior to engaging in price competition. However, the Cournot model may be less appropriate for R&D intensive tech firms for which capacity constraint is less relevant. Nonetheless, our main results are robust to Bertrand competition with differentiated products. The reason is that regardless of the mode of competition, the MNE will have incentives to relax competition as its licensing revenues depend on the licensee’s revenues, which induces a semi-collusive outcome. This incentive has the effects of impairing consumer welfare in both Cournot and Bertrand models (see Fauli-Oller and Sandonis, 2002). Note also that the MNE may not have incentives to drive the rival firm out with differentiated products because industry revenue maximization requires both products in the market.

Our Cournot framework can also be applied to platform firms with ad-funded business models in two-sided markets. These firms provide services free to consumers but derive revenues from advertising. They choose the amount of advertising (ad load) which determines the advertising price. As the marginal cost of serving consumers is close to zero in digital markets, we can also interpret cost-reducing innovations as quality-enhancing.

Although our model has shed new light on the link between licensing and profit-shifting, further analysis on this topic is essential. A potential extension would be policy analyses focusing more on patents (e.g., the patent box).Footnote 35 Although several empirical studies have focused on these kinds of policies rapidly prevailing in Europe, theoretical studies have not been very satisfactory.